SUBSIDY
RATIONALISATION IS A FAILED NEO-LIBERAL POLICY
Subsidy Rationalization
The Barisan Nasional GE13
honeymoon came to an abrupt end when Prime Minister Dato Seri Najib Tun Razak
announced on 2nd September 2013 an increase by 20 cents of RON 95
and diesel bringing the price to RM2.10 and RM2.00 a liter respectively. The
Prime Minister said that subsidy rationalization is back on the table when
Budget 2014 is unveiled this coming October. I raise, in the recent
parliamentary session, that removing fuel subsidies and providing targeted
subsidies such as BR1M is a failed neo-liberal policy. Deputy Finance Minister
Datuk Ahmad Maslan in reply repeated that subsidy rationalization is needed to address
the fiscal deficit and the Government prefers providing targeted subsidies to
the poor through programmes such as BR1M than universal subsidies that benefit
the rich. He unfortunately did not respond to the issue that neo-liberal
policies had failed.
Some quarters believe the
Government is correct to remove subsidies because of increasingly high global
market price of petroleum and that targeted cash subsidies is more efeective. Dr
Lim Teck Ghee issued a timely reminder that subsidies have an important role to
play in providing a safety net to vulnerable groups. He said in pushing for a
free market system without due attention to the structural defects of our
political economy, proponents of the neo-liberal ideology run the risk of
throwing out the baby with the bathwater.[1]
I like to add that shifting to targeted cash subsidies does not reduce poverty.
Only a redistributive policy can do this. Removing fuel subsidies and providing
targeted cash subsidies has its own challenges including problems of
identification of the target group, high administrative costs, inflationary
effect on prices following fuel increases, increase speculative activities and
less market stability. We should learn from the bitter experiences and
sufferings of those who implemented the neo-liberal policies by rejecting them.
IMF and World Bank Recommendations
The Government is
repeating the International Monetary Fund (“IMF”) and the World Bank arguments
for subsidy rationalization. IMF has often said and recently repeated in an
article dated January 28 2013, that while fuel subsidies are aimed at
protecting consumers, subsidies aggravate fiscal imbalances, crowd-out priority
public spending, and depress private investment, including in the energy sector.
IMF said that subsidies also distort resource allocation by encouraging
excessive energy consumption, artificially promoting capital-intensive
industries, reducing incentives for investment in renewable energy, and
accelerating the depletion of natural resources. According to IMF, most subsidy
benefits are captured by higher-income households reinforcing inequality. Even
future generations are affected through the damaging effects of increased
energy consumption on global warming.[2]
The Washington Consensus and Neo-Liberal Policies
I have read several
articles and comments that because the Government’s subsidy rationalization is adopting
IMF and the World Bank policies, subsidy rationalization must therefore be good
for Malaysians. It is not necessarily true. In order to understand the impact
and effect of the subsidy rationalization policy I have carried out some
research on this matter. I like to share this research. I believe it is necessary
for Malaysians to understand and know the objectives and policies of IMF, the
World Bank, the US Treasury and other institutions in Washington known as “the
Washington Consensus” and the experience of those that implemented the
neo-liberal policies. I like to share the views of those who believe the
Washington Consensus and Neo-Liberal policies are responsible for the poverty
and inequality increase in the countries that implemented them. The Washington
Consensus forced these governments to implement the neo-liberal policies as
part of the conditions for loans given. Critics blame these neo-liberal
policies for the misery and dislocation suffered by the unfortunate citizens of
these countries.
The term “Washington
Consensus” was coined in 1989 by John Williamson. It was introduced in a period
when the Keynesian dominance in economic theory and policy had collapsed and
neo-liberalism was promoted by Reagan and Thatcher administrations in the US
and UK. Williamson summarizes these neo-liberal policy prescriptions in ten
propositions:-
1. The imposition of fiscal
discipline;
2. The redirection of public
expenditure priorities towards other fields;
3. The introduction of tax
reforms that would lower marginal rates and broaden the tax base;
4. The liberalization of
interest rate;
5. A competitive exchange
rate;
6. The liberalization of
trade;
7. The liberalization of
inflows of foreign direct investment;
8. The privatization of
state-owned economic enterprises;
9. The deregulation of
economic activities;
10. The creation of a secure
environment for property rights;[3]
The theoretical
foundations of these proposals are those advanced by the neo-liberal economic
theory. According to this theory, economies are in crisis because of
impediments to the free operation of the market. The impediments came from the
overinflated interventionist Keynesian state and its expansionary and
redistributive policies that deformed market data and signals. The solution,
according to the neo-liberal mantra, would be the withdrawal of the state from
the economy and the reinstatement of the unhindered operations of the market.
Therefore, fiscal discipline should be imposed on public activities and a
return to the balanced budgets (as opposed to the Keynesian deficit and
expansionary budgets). The now limited public budget expenditure should be
directed towards fields that cover its costs (possibly through the imposition
of compensation payments) and would support private entrepreneurship instead of
paying for public works and redistributive policies. Subsequently, the tax
system should be reformed so as not to hit hard business profits and the
incomes of the upper strata, which were conceived as the locomotive of the
economy. Additionally, the operation of the financial system should be
liberated from the state and be left to the free operation of the market
forces. Thus, the interest rate should be determined more or less
competitively. The withdrawal of the state from the economy required, also, the
privatization of all activities and enterprises that were state-owned and
directed, the limitation to a minimum of all state regulations and adequate
guarantees that there would not be violations of property rights (as it had
happened previously with nationalizations).
The second generation
neo-liberal theory emphasized the opening of economies, the liberalization of
international trade, capital movements and financial activities. Thus
protectionist measures had to be abolished and free trade movements had to be
secured. Last but not least, international financial transactions and
primarily, the exchange rate of the currency had to be set according to market
prerogatives and not by state policies.
Neo-Liberal Policies Criticized for Increased Poverty and
Inequality
It has been said that many
developing nations are in debt and poverty partly due to these policies of IMF
and the World Bank. Their programmes have been heavily criticized for many
years for resulting in poverty. In addition, for developing or third world
countries, there has been an increased dependency on the richer nations. This
is despite the IMF and World Bank’s claim that they will reduce poverty.
Following neo-liberalism the Washington Consensus spearheaded, Structural
Adjustment Policies that were imposed to ensure debt repayment and economic
restructuring. However, the way it has happened has required poor countries to
reduce spending on things like health, education and development, while debt
repayment and other economic policies have been made the priority.[4]
After the first years of
implementation of the Washington Consensus policies and reforms there was a
growing sense, among friends and foes, that it failed its promises. More
specifically, from the late 1990s and onwards, the Washington Consensus was
facing major difficulties regarding a number of issues, which were not included
in its declared objectives but are crucial for the development process. It was
criticized by UNICEF for failing to implement adjustment process with a “human
face”, and thus, for causing social upheavals.[5]
Additionally, it was criticized for failing to deliver significant advances in
performance, let alone development. Several studies argued that its policies
led to an increased in poverty and inequality both between developed and
developing and less developed economies and within themselves. Additionally,
the apparent inability of developing and less developed economies to catch-up
the level of growth of the developed ones and, in many cases, the increase of
the gap between them were attributed also to the policies instigated by the
Washington Consensus.
Neo-Liberal Policies view Poverty and Inequality as of
Secondary Order
For almost all critics,
Washington Consensus and the inability of the neo-liberal policies to address
issues of poverty and inequality lay on its analytical perspective. The
Washington Consensus held the view that poverty and inequality were problems of
a secondary order, which more or less would have been alleviated once the
market was free to operate undisturbed by the impediments, then the free
operation of capital, domestically, but mainly internationally will provide all
the stimulation and the efficiency necessary for feasible development. Against
this market-fundamentalist presumption, most of the critics point out during
the last twenty years of the 20th century after implementation of the
Washington Consensus neo-liberal policies and structural changes there was a
marked increase of poverty and inequality.[6]
Washington Consensus Accepts Shortcomings
The Structural Adjustment
Policies were indeed a contraction policy. According to Ali Dini and Victor
Lippit, a visiting scholar and professor respectively of the Economics
Department of University of California-Riverside, the consequences of these
policies were falling capital accumulation due to falling public expenditure
and rising poverty mainly due to liberalizing food prices and falling real
income.[7]
World Bank and IMF in a joint study in 1989 pointed out[8]:
“Declining
per capital incomes accompanied by worsening social indicators, particularly
sub Saharan Africa and Latin America… Some of the poor did benefit, but many
vulnerable groups were hurt by measures associated with adjustment. By the
mid-1980s, it became clear that given the time and effort required to turn
deeply troubled economies around, it would be morally, politically and
economically unacceptable to wait for resumed growth alone to reduce poverty”
In 1990 Michael Camdessus,
managing director of IMF, accepted:
“..the
recognition that macroeconomic policies can have strong effects on the
distribution of income and on social equity and welfare. A responsible
adjustment program must take these effects into account, particularly as they
impinge on the most vulnerable or disadvantaged groups in society”[9]
IMF and the World Bank thereafter
responded to these criticisms by proposing the removal of subsidies with cash subsidies
to the targeted poor to compensate for the negative effects of the Structural
Adjustment Programmes. Scholars argued that the Structural Adjustment
Programmes with cash subsidies to the poor is insufficient and state
intervention is necessary to provide public goods including health, education
and job creation.
The need for state
intervention was confirmed during the 2006 to 2008 world food crisis. People in
some developing countries died because of their inability to pay the high food
prices due to their fixed nominal income. According to FAO at least 100 million
people suffer the risk of hunger. In the words of Josette Sheeran (2008) the
head of the UN’s World Food Program:
“This
is the new face of hunger… There is food on the shelves but people are priced
out of the market. There is vulnerability in urban areas we have not seen
before. There are food riots in countries where we have not seen them before”
The world food crisis
confirms that markets including food markets have to be governed and state
intervention is necessary.
Legacy of Neo-Liberal
Policies and the Arab Spring
On New Year’s Day 2012,
Nigeria joined Guinea, Cameroon, Ghana and Chad to remove fuel subsidies in
accordance with a directive from the IMF. Much to the dismay of the population
of these nations, the prices of fuel and transport nearly tripled over night,
causing widespread violence on the streets.[10]
Neo-Liberal Policies pushed by the Washington Consensus on Ben Ali of Tunisia
and Hosni Mubarak of Egypt stoke the fires of Arab Spring. In both Tunisia and
Egypt, the neo-liberal policies of the pre-revolutionary period fueled the
social protests. Privatization adopted by Hosni Mubarak threw hundreds of
thousands in Egypt out of work into impoverishment. Cuts in public health and
education, galloping food-price inflation sparked bread riots in 2008. The
lightning rod for the Tunisian revolution was the death of Muhamed Bouaziz- a
young man driven to suicide by economic hardship and state harassment. The
uprising which followed brought down the dictatorship of Ben Ali.
In August 2012 the Mohammed
Morsi government approached the IMF for a US4.8 billion loan. Getting the loan
was critical. If Egypt could raise the funds, it would be in a better position
to borrow from other sources. IMF calculated Egypt needed at least US 10 to 12
billion to survive another year. With more than 40% of the people living on
less than US$2 a day and prices of essential goods had risen by 25% on average
a year, IMF insisted on deep cuts to subsidies for fuel and bread. Egyptian
workers saw this as a betrayal of the revolution’s demand for “Bread, Freedom
and Social Justice” and launched a series of strikes and protests against the
subsidy cuts.[11]
The rest as they say is history.
Malaysians Must Take Heed
Malaysians must take heed
that the Washington Consensus neo-liberal policies have missed the mark. Jeffrey
D. Sachs, economist and director of Earth Institute at Columbia University and
the United Nations Millennium Project said economists have learned a great deal
during the past few years one is the need for good governance[12]
and:
“The
other major insight is that although the most powerful mechanism for reducing
extreme poverty is to encourage overall growth. A rising tide does not
necessarily lift all boats. Average income can rise, but if the income is
distributed unevenly the poor may benefit little, and pockets of extreme
poverty may persist (especially in geographically disadvantaged regions).
Moreover, growth is not simply a free-market phenomenon. It requires basic
government services: infrastructure, health, education, and scientific and
technological innovation. Thus, many recommendations of the past two decades
emanating from Washington–that government in low-income countries should cut
back on their spending to make room for the private sector-miss the point.
Government spending, directed at investment in critical areas, is itself a
vital spur to growth, especially if its effects are to reach the poorest of the
poor.”
Malaysians have the good
fortune to learn that the neo-liberal experiment has failed and should not
repeat the mistakes as Jeffrey Sachs said:
“The
whole thing was based on the idea that if you take away the government for the
poorest of the poor that somehow these markets will solve the problems… But
markets can’t step in and won’t step in when people have nothing. And if you take
away help, you leave them to die”
Let’s not throw out the
baby with the bathwater.
William Leong Jee Keen
Member of Parliament
Selayang
[1] Look Before You Cut: It’s the Government that’s the biggest subsidy
burden Not the Poor http://www.malaysia-chronicle.com/index.php?option=com_k2&view-item&id=41835:look-before-you-cut-its-the-govt-thats-the-biggest-subsidy-burden-not-the-poor
[2] Energy Subsidy reforms- Lessons and Implications; IMF Policy Paper;
January 28, 2013 http://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2013/012813.pdf
[3] Reform, reform the reforms or simply regression? The ‘Washington
Consensus’ and its Critics
[4] Structural Adjustment-a Major Cause of Poverty – Global Issues
http://www.globalissues.org/article/3/structural-adjustment-amajor-cause-of-poverty
[5] UNICEF report “Adjustment with a Human Face” 1987
[6] Reform, reform the reforms or simply regression? The ‘Washington
Consensus’ and its Critics
[7] Food Subsidies, Growth and Poverty A Critique on Neoliberal
Institutional Structure Ali Dini Visiting Scholar at Economics Department of
University of California-Riverside and Victor Lippit Professor at Economics
Department of University of California-Riverside. http://economics.ucr.edu/repec/ucr/wpaper/09-12.pdf
[8] IMF/World Bank Report quoted from IMF Survey 3 April 1989
[9] Camdessus M “Speech to US Chamber of Commerce 26 March 1990
[10] The IMF and US African Command (AFRICOM) Join Hands in the Plunder
of the African Continent by Nile Bowie Global Research 6 January 2012
[11] Mena Solidarity Network menasolidaritynetwork.com http://menasolidaritynetwork.files.wordpress.com/2013/07mena-a5_briefing13_print_web.pdf
[12] Can Extreme Poverty Be Eliminated by Jeffery D. Sachs 2005
Scientific American Inc.
It's a pity that well-researched and thoughtful pieces are not cohered and delivered more comprehensively under a more permanent framework that will reach a wider audience in order to develop critical thinking so needed to expand the democratic space of moderates without whom the destabilizing forces at present will swarm to seize the mantle. The first thing that must be done and within the next three months is to get more organized. Individual efforts here and there do not a credible and winning voice make. And that is needed more than ever to offer a different perspective and more choices to the fence-sitters who can make and break a situation already loaded against good change by the gerrymandering of constituencies that remains the main obstacle to a better government.
ReplyDelete